THE EDGE WEEKLY ISSUE#992
THE WEEK OF DECEMBER 9 – DECEMBER 15, 2013
AFTER THE Storm: By Nouriel
Roubini
It is widely agreed that
a series of collapsing housing market bubbles triggered the global financial
crisis of 2008/2009, along with the severe recession that followed. While the US is the best known case,
a combination of lax regulation and supervision of banks and low policy
interest rates fuelled similar bubbles in UK , Spain , Ireland , Iceland and Dubai .
Now, five years later,
signs of frothiness, if not out right bubbles, are reappearing in housing
markets in Switzerland, Sweden, Norway, Finland, France, Germany, Canada,
Australia, New Zealand and, back for an encore, the UK (well, London). In emerging markets, bubbles are appearing in
Hong Kong , Singapore , China and Israel , and in major urban
centres in Turkey , India , Indonesia and Brazil .
Signs that home prices
are entering bubble territory in these economies include fast-rising home
prices, high and rising price-to-income ratios, and high levels
of mortgage debt as a share of household debt.
In most advanced
economies, bubbles are being inflated by very low short and long-term interest
rates. Given anaemic GDP growth, high
unemployment and low inflation, the wall of liquidity generated by conventional
and unconventional monetary easing is driving up asset prices, starting with
home prices.
The situation is more
varied in emerging market economies. Some
that have high per capital income – e.g. Israel , Hong Kong , Singapore – have low inflation and
want to maintain low policy interest rates to prevent exchange-rate
appreciation against major currencies.
Others are characterized
by high inflation (even above the central bank target, as in Turkey , India , Indonesia and Brazil ). In China and India , savings are going into
home purchases because financial repression leaves households with few other
assets that provide a good hedge again inflation. Rapid urbanization in many emerging
markets has also driven up home prices as demand outstrips supply.
With central banks –
especially in advanced economies and the high-income emerging economies – wary
of using policy rates to fight bubbles, most countries are relying on macro-prudential
regulation and supervision of the financial system to address frothy housing
markets.
That means lower loan-to-value
ratios, stricter mortgage-underwriting standards, limits on
second-home financing, higher counter-cyclical capital buffers for
mortgage lending, higher permanent capital charges for mortgages, and restrictions
on the use of pension funds for down payments on home purchases.
In most economies, these
macro-prudential policies are modest, owing to policy-makers’ political
constraints: households, real estate developers and elected officials protest
loudly when the central bank or the regulatory authority in charge of financial
stability tries to take away the punch bowl of liquidity. They complain bitterly about regulators’ “interference”
with the free market, property rights and the sacrosanct ideal of home ownership. Thus, the political economy of housing
finance limits regulators’ ability to do the right thing.
To be clear,
macro-prudential restrictions are certainly called for but they have been
inadequate to control housing bubbles. With
short and long-term interest rates so low, mortgage-credit restrictions seem to
have a limited effect on the incentives to borrow to purchase a home. Moreover, the higher the gap between official
interest rates and the higher rates on mortgage lending as a result of macro-prudential
restrictions, the more room there is for regulatory arbitrage.
E.g. if loan-to-value
ratios are reduced and down payments on home purchases are higher, households
may have an incentive to borrow from friends and family – or from banks in the
form of personal unsecured loans – to finance down payments.
After all, though
home-price inflation has slowed modestly in some countries, home prices in
general are still rising in economies where macro-prudential restrictions on
mortgage-lending are being used. So long
as official policy interest rates – and thus long-term mortgage rates – remain
low, such restrictions are not as binding as they otherwise would be.
But the global economy’s
new housing bubbles may not be about to burst just yet because the forces
feeding them – especially easy money and the need to hedge against
inflation – are still fully operative.
Moreover, many banking systems
have bigger capital buffers than in the past, enabling them to absorb losses
from a correction in home prices, and, in most countries, households’ equity in
their homes is greater than it was in the US subprime mortgage
bubble. But the higher home
prices rise, the further they will fall – and the greater the collateral
economic and financial damage will be – when the bubble deflates.
In countries where
non-recourse loans allow borrowers to walk away from a mortgage when its value
exceeds that of their home, the housing burst may lead to massive defaults and
banking crises.
In countries (e.g. Sweden ) where recourse loans
allow seizure of household income to enforce payment of mortgage obligations,
private consumption may plummet as debt payments (and eventually rising
interest rates) crowd out discretionary spending. Either way, the result would be the same: recession
and stagnation.
What we are witnessing in
many countries looks like a slow-motion replay of the last housing market train
wreck. And, like last time, the bigger
the bubbles become, the nastier the collision with reality will be. – Project
Syndicate
No comments:
Post a Comment